Go to the Globe and Mail homepage

Jump to main navigationJump to main content

Report on Business

Economy Lab

Delving into the forces that shape our living standards
Best Business Blog, EPPY awards, 2011 and 2012

Entry archive:

Economy Lab has moved

Only Globe Unlimited members will now have access to a wide range of insightful commentary
and analysis on the economy and markets previously offered on this page.


Globe Unlimited subscribers will be able to read these columns,
written by some of Canada’s most deeply respected economists,
such as Christopher Ragan, Sheryl King, Andrew Jackson, and Clement Gignac,
as part of our ROB INSIGHT section.


All of our readers will still be able to browse the Economy Lab archives and read our
broader coverage of economic data and news by accessing their 10 free articles a month.


Learn more about Globe Unlimited and how to subscribe.

(Franz Pfluegl/iStockphoto)
(Franz Pfluegl/iStockphoto)

Economy Lab

Subsidies put the R&D horse before the innovation cart Add to ...

The logic behind subsidies for research and development (R&D) activities seems straightforward enough: R&D creates new ideas and new technologies. These new technologies can then be used to increase productivity, wages and incomes. A casual glance at the data would seem to confirm the link: high levels of R&D are generally associated with dynamic, fast-growing economies. If government can help this process along, then it should.

More related to this story

But what if this story is simply confusing cause and effect? What if the real reason that firms in a dynamic, growing economy invest so much effort into R&D is that they are reacting to the market signals that a dynamic growing economy provides?

For firms operating in a dynamic environment, the advantages of investing in R&D are clear enough: it is more profitable to be at the leading edge of a fast-growing economy. And the costs of not doing R&D are equally clear: dominant firms who skimp on R&D don’t stay on top for long. For firms in these dynamic economies, R&D is not only a source of new profits, it’s also a matter of survival.

Let’s think now of a less-than-dynamic economy where firms in difficulty can often count on a government bail-out to keep them going, where government procurement policies shield them from foreign competitors (or even from competitors from another province or city) and where there is a rich kaleidoscope of government programs that offer a wide range of opportunities to obtain public funding. In short, an economy not entirely unlike Canada’s.

Investing in R&D wouldn’t do much to ensure survival in this economy. Instead, firms would find that it is much more important to invest in lobbying and consultant services in order to fully exploit the opportunities for government funding. Adding R&D subsidies to the mix would simply add another playing field for this game.

People respond to incentives. If the government gets into the business of giving money to firms that undertake activities that the government deems “close enough to R&D to get public funding”, then that money won’t be left on the table. But if the reason for carrying out R&D-like activities is the availability of public funding, then actual innovation ends up being more of a coincidence than an objective.

If high levels of R&D are the effect of a dynamic economy and not their cause, we shouldn’t be surprised that R&D subsidies aren’t producing the desired results.

In the know

Most popular video »

Highlights

More from The Globe and Mail

Most Popular Stories